Joel Mokyr
Joel Mokyr | |
---|---|
Born | |
Nationality | Israeli American |
Spouse | Margalit Mokyr |
Children | 2[3] |
Awards | Heineken Award for History (2006) Balzan Prize (2015) |
Academic background | |
Alma mater | Yale University (MPhil, PhD) Hebrew University of Jerusalem (BA) |
Doctoral advisor | William N. Parker John C. H. Fei |
Academic work | |
Discipline | Economic history |
Institutions | Northwestern University |
Doctoral students | Avner Greif[1] |
Main interests | Economic history of Europe |
Influenced | Cormac Ó Gráda[2] |
Joel Mokyr (born 26 July 1946) is a Dutch-born American-Israeli economic historian who has been a professor of economics and history and the Robert H. Strotz Professor of Arts and Sciences at Northwestern University since 1994.[4] Since 2001, he has also been the Sackler Professorial Fellow at the Eitan Berglas School of Economics at Tel Aviv University.[4]
Early life and education
[edit]Mokyr was born in Leiden in 1946, into a family of Dutch Jews who had survived the Holocaust.[5] His father, a civil servant, died of cancer when Mokyr was one year old, and so he was raised by his mother in Haifa, Israel.[5] He received a BA in economics and history from the Hebrew University of Jerusalem in 1968.[4] He received an MPhil in economics from Yale University in 1972, and a PhD in economics from Yale in 1974, writing a dissertation titled Industrial Growth and Stagnation in the Low Countries, 1800-1850 under the supervision of William N. Parker, Lloyd G. Reynolds, and John C.H. Fei.[6]
Career
[edit]Mokyr was an acting instructor at Yale University between 1972 and 1973, and became an assistant professor at Northwestern University in 1974, where he has remained ever since.[5] Since then, he has chair or co-chaired over 50 doctoral student theses.[7] He has been the editor-in-chief of the Princeton Economic History of the Western World (a book series published by Princeton University Press) since 1993, and was a co-editor of the Journal of Economic History from 1994 to 1998.[4] He was President of the Economic History Association from 2002 to 2003.[4]
Mokyr was elected to the American Academy of Arts and Sciences in 1996, and was elected a Fellow of the Econometric Society in 2011.[4][8][9] He was elected a foreign member of the Royal Netherlands Academy of Arts and Sciences in 2001, whose biennial Heineken Award for History he received in 2006.[10][11] He won the 2015 Balzan International Prize for economic history.[12]
Research
[edit]Industrial Revolution
[edit]Mokyr posits that the Industrial Revolution was the result of culture and institutions.[13] He argues that the root of modernity is in "the emergence of a belief in the usefulness of progress", and that "it was a turning point when intellectuals started to conceive of knowledge as cumulative".[14]
Mokyr furthermore argues that political fragmentation (the presence of a large number of European states) made it possible for heterodox ideas to thrive, as entrepreneurs, innovators, ideologues, and heretics could easily flee to a neighbouring state in the event that the one state would try to suppress their ideas and activities. This is what set Europe apart from the technologically advanced, large unitary empires such as China and India. China had both a printing press and movable type, and India had similar levels of scientific and technological achievement as Europe in 1700, yet the Industrial Revolution would occur in Europe, not China or India. In Europe, political fragmentation was coupled with an "integrated market for ideas" where Europe's intellectuals used the lingua franca of Latin, had a shared intellectual basis in Europe's classical heritage and the pan-European institution of the Republic of Letters.[15]
A Culture of Growth
[edit]Mokyr presents his explanations for the Industrial Revolution in the 2016 book A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern Economy. The book has received positive reviews. Deirdre McCloskey described it as a "brilliant book... It’s long, but consistently interesting, even witty. It sustains interest right down to page 337... The book is not beach reading. But you will finish it impressively learned about how we got to where we are in the modern world."[16] In her review, McCloskey furthermore lauded Mokyr as a "Nobel-worthy economic scientist".[16]
In a review published in Nature, Brad DeLong found that while he favored other explanations for the Industrial Revolution, "I would not be greatly surprised if I were wrong, and Mokyr's brief...turned out to be the most broadly correct analysis...A Culture of Growth is certainly making me rethink."[17]
Cambridge economic historian Victoria Bateman wrote, "In pointing to growth-boosting factors that go beyond either the state or the market, Mokyr's book is very welcome. It could also feed into discussions about the scientific community post-Brexit. By reviving the focus on culture it will, however, prove controversial, particularly among economists."[18] An article in The Economist pointed out that a fine definitional distinction had to be considered between “culture as ideas, socially learned” and “culture as inheritance transmitted genetically”.[19] The book has also been reviewed favorably by Diane Coyle,[20] Peer Vries,[21] Mark Koyama,[22] Enrico Spolaore,[23] and The Economist.[24] Geoffrey Hodgson criticized the book for placing "too much explanatory weight" on "too few extraordinary people."[25]
Resistance to new technologies
[edit]Mokyr outlined three reasons why societies resist new technologies:
- Incumbents who fear a threat to their power and economic rents
- Concern about broader social and political repercussions ("unintended ripple effects")
- Risk and loss aversion: new technologies often have "unanticipated and unknowable consequences"
"These three motives often merge and create powerful forces that use political power and persuasion to thwart innovations. As a result, technological progress does not follow a linear and neat trajectory. It is, as social constructionists have been trying to tell us for decades, a profoundly political process."[26]
Quotes
[edit]- "Being teleological is the second worst thing you can be as a Historian. The worst is being Eurocentric."
Works
[edit]- 1976: Industrialization in the Low Countries, 1795–1850
- 1983: Why Ireland Starved: An Analytical and Quantitative Study of Irish Poverty, 1800–1851
- 1985: The Economics of the Industrial Revolution (ed.)
- 1990: Twenty Five Centuries of Technological Change: An Historical Survey
- 1990: The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress
- Review article: "The Great Conundrum", The Journal of Modern History Vol 62, No. 1, March 1990
- 1991: The Vital One: Essays in Honor of Jonathan Hughes (ed.)
- 1993: The British Industrial Revolution: an Economic Perspective (ed.)
- 2002: The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy
- 2003: The Oxford University Press Encyclopedia of Economic History (Editor in chief)
- 2009: The Invention of Enterprise: Entrepreneurship from Ancient Mesopotamia to Modern Times (Co-editor)
- 2009: The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain 1700–1850
- 2010: The Birth of Modern Europe: Culture and Economy, 1400–1800: Essay in Honor of Jan de Vries(co-editor with Laura Cruz)
- 2016: A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern Economy
- 2017: Economics in the Test of Time: Issues in Economic History (with Amira Ofer), in Hebrew, 2 volumes.
- TBA: Why Britain? A new view of the Industrial Revolution. With Morgan Kelly and Cormac Ó Gráda
- TBA: Two Paths to Prosperity: Culture and Institutions in Europe and China, 1200-2000. With Avner Greif and Guido Tabellini
References
[edit]- ^ Greif, Avner (1991). "The Organization of Long-Distance Trade: Reputation and Coalitions in the Geniza Documents and Genoa During the Eleventh and Twelfth Centuries". Journal of Economic History. 51 (2): 459. doi:10.1017/S0022050700039097. S2CID 154791174.
- ^ de Bromhead, Alan (Winter 2017). "An Interview with Cormac Ó Gráda" (PDF). The Newsletter of the Cliometric Society. 31 (2): 20–23. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2017-07-24. Retrieved 2018-01-27.
- ^ "The Gifts of Athena" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 1 August 2014. Retrieved 11 March 2017.
- ^ a b c d e f https://bpb-us-e1.wpmucdn.com/sites.northwestern.edu/dist/3/1222/files/2021/08/Mokyr-2021-CV.pdf[bare URL]
- ^ a b c Aeppel, Timothy. "Economists Debate: Has All the Important Stuff Already Been Invented?". Wall Street Journal. ISSN 0099-9660. Retrieved 12 January 2017.
- ^ "Curriculum Vitae" (PDF). Northwestern University. June 2016. Retrieved 27 January 2018.
- ^ a b "Curriculum vitae" (PDF). economics.northwestern.edu. August 2021. Retrieved 31 August 2021.
- ^ "Member Directory | American Academy of Arts and Sciences". www.amacad.org. Retrieved 2024-01-23.
- ^ "Current Fellows". www.econometricsociety.org. Retrieved 2024-01-23.
- ^ "Joël Mokyr". Royal Netherlands Academy of Arts and Sciences. Archived from the original on 13 February 2016. Retrieved 13 February 2016.
- ^ "Joel Mokyr (1946), USA". Royal Netherlands Academy of Arts and Sciences. Archived from the original on 22 July 2020.
- ^ "Joel Mokyr". Northwestern University. Retrieved 27 January 2018.
- ^ Mokyr, Joel (1 June 2005). "The Intellectual Origins of Modern Economic Growth". The Journal of Economic History. 65 (2): 285–351. doi:10.1017/S0022050705000112 (inactive 1 November 2024). ISSN 1471-6372. S2CID 54225284.
{{cite journal}}
: CS1 maint: DOI inactive as of November 2024 (link) - ^ Mokyr, Joel. "Progress Isn't Natural". The Atlantic. Retrieved 19 November 2016.
- ^ Mokyr, Joel (2018). Mokyr, J.: A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern Economy. Princeton University Press. ISBN 9780691180960. Retrieved 9 March 2017.
- ^ a b "Economic history: ideas that built the world". www.prospectmagazine.co.uk. Archived from the original on 8 May 2021. Retrieved 11 March 2017.
- ^ DeLong, Brad (27 October 2016). "Economic history: The roots of growth". Nature. 538 (7626): 456–57. Bibcode:2016Natur.538..456D. doi:10.1038/538456a. ISSN 0028-0836.
- ^ "A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern Economy, by Joel Mokyr". Times Higher Education. 6 October 2016. Retrieved 11 March 2017.
- ^ "Cultural change can unlock the economic potential of people and ideas". The Economist. Retrieved 24 July 2019.
- ^ "A Culture of Growth by Joel Mokyr — why did the Industrial Revolution happen?". Financial Times. 21 October 2016. Retrieved 11 March 2017.
- ^ Vries, Peer (10 December 2016). "The Culture of Capitalism". Foreign Affairs. ISSN 0015-7120. Retrieved 11 March 2017.
- ^ "Book Review: A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern Economy, by Joel Mokyr". The Independent Institute. Retrieved 2017-12-11.
- ^ Spolaore, Enrico (2020). "Commanding Nature by Obeying Her: A Review Essay on Joel Mokyr's A Culture of Growth". Journal of Economic Literature. 58 (3): 777–792. doi:10.1257/jel.20191460. ISSN 0022-0515. S2CID 226193779.
- ^ "The role of ideas in the "great divergence"". The Economist. Retrieved 11 March 2017.
- ^ Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2021). "Culture and institutions: a review of Joel Mokyr's A Culture of Growth". Journal of Institutional Economics. 18: 159–168. doi:10.1017/S1744137421000588. ISSN 1744-1374.
- ^ "Innovation and Its Enemies: Why People Resist New Technologies". eh.net. Retrieved 12 January 2017.
- ^ Joel Mokyr, Curriculum Vitae, wcas.northwestern.edu; accessed 12 January 2016.
External links
[edit]- Profile, Northwestern.edu; accessed 21 January 2016.
- 1946 births
- Living people
- Economic historians
- 21st-century American economists
- 20th-century American economists
- Dutch Jews
- American people of Dutch-Jewish descent
- Jewish American historians
- Yale University alumni
- Northwestern University faculty
- Fellows of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences
- Members of the Royal Netherlands Academy of Arts and Sciences
- People from Leiden
- Winners of the Heineken Prize
- Fellows of the Econometric Society
- Historians of Ireland
- Corresponding fellows of the British Academy
- Presidents of the Economic History Association