The parable of the broken window was introduced by French economist Frédéric Bastiat in his 1850 essay "That Which Is Seen, and That Which Is Not Seen" ("Ce qu'on voit et ce qu'on ne voit pas") to illustrate why destruction, and the money spent to recover from destruction, is not actually a net benefit to society.
The parable seeks to show how opportunity costs, as well as the law of unintended consequences, affect economic activity in ways that are unseen or ignored. The belief that destruction is good for the economy is consequently known as the broken window fallacy or glazier's fallacy.
Parable
editBastiat's original parable of the broken window from "Ce qu'on voit et ce qu'on ne voit pas" (1850):
Have you ever witnessed the anger of the good shopkeeper, James Goodfellow, when his careless son has happened to break a pane of glass? If you have been present at such a scene, you will most assuredly bear witness to the fact that every one of the spectators, were there even thirty of them, by common consent apparently, offered the unfortunate owner this invariable consolation – "It is an ill wind that blows nobody good. Everybody must live, and what would become of the glaziers if panes of glass were never broken?"
Now, this form of condolence contains an entire theory, which it will be well to show up in this simple case, seeing that it is precisely the same as that which, unhappily, regulates the greater part of our economical institutions.
Suppose it cost six francs to repair the damage, and you say that the accident brings six francs to the glazier's trade – that it encourages that trade to the amount of six francs – I grant it; I have not a word to say against it; you reason justly. The glazier comes, performs his task, receives his six francs, rubs his hands, and, in his heart, blesses the careless child. All this is that which is seen.
But if, on the other hand, you come to the conclusion, as is too often the case, that it is a good thing to break windows, that it causes money to circulate, and that the encouragement of industry in general will be the result of it, you will oblige me to call out, "Stop there! Your theory is confined to that which is seen; it takes no account of that which is not seen."
It is not seen that as our shopkeeper has spent six francs upon one thing, he cannot spend them upon another. It is not seen that if he had not had a window to replace, he would, perhaps, have replaced his old shoes, or added another book to his library. In short, he would have employed his six francs in some way, which this accident has prevented.[1]
Interpretations and evidence
editBastiat's argument
editSuppose it were discovered that the little boy was actually hired by the glazier, and paid a franc for every window he broke. Suddenly the same act would be regarded as theft: the glazier was breaking windows to force people to hire his services. Yet the facts observed by the onlookers remain true: the glazier benefits from the business at the expense of the baker, the tailor, and so on.
Bastiat argues that society endorses activities that are morally equivalent to the glazier hiring a boy to break windows for him:
Whence we arrive at this unexpected conclusion: "Society loses the value of things which are uselessly destroyed;" and we must assent to a maxim which will make the hair of protectionists stand on end – To break, to spoil, to waste, is not to encourage national labour; or, more briefly, "destruction is not profit."
What will you say, Moniteur Industriel[2] – what will you say, disciples of good M. F. Chamans, who has calculated with so much precision how much trade would gain by the burning of Paris, from the number of houses it would be necessary to rebuild?[1]
Bastiat is not addressing production – he is addressing the stock of wealth. In other words, Bastiat does not merely look at the immediate but at the longer effects of breaking the window. Bastiat takes into account the consequences of breaking the window for society as a whole, rather than for just one group.[3][4]
Austrian theorists cite this fallacy, saying it is a common element of popular thinking. The 20th century American economist Henry Hazlitt devoted a chapter to the fallacy in his book Economics in One Lesson.[5]
Cost of disasters
editThe broken-window scenario is used as an analogy for destruction by natural disasters.[6] Disasters disrupt economic activity.[7] The economic effects of natural disasters are varied.[8]
Countries are more likely to have GDP fall after a disaster if they have more unemployment, more poverty, less effective local and national governments and institutions, and weaker economic and diplomatic connections. Countries are more likely to have a GDP boost and recover quickly from a disaster if they retain a skilled workforce and the ability to mobilize resources for reconstruction, including resources from outside the disaster area.[9][10] On the one hand, prompt recovery has been attributed to prompt insurance and aid payments, with the contrast between Hurricane Andrew and Hurricane Katrina as an anecdotal example. On the other hand, slow recovery has been blamed on predatory behaviour, with those unharmed or less-harmed by the disaster taking advantage of those more harmed.[8]
Areas that have had repeated disasters tend to invest more in skills and education (possibly because this is preferred to riskier investment in infrastructure, which might be destroyed again), and they tend to have a higher total factor productivity (possibly also because infrastructure destroyed in disasters is replaced with better infrastructure, as, for instance, in the Great Fire of London). These tendencies could in theory lead to longer-term economic benefits (which may cause GDP growth).[8][11]
There is some evidence that geological disasters do more economic harm than climate-related disasters, in the long term. Geological disasters, such as landslides and earthquakes, happen with little immediate warning and kill many people. Climate-related disasters, such as hurricanes, are more predictable on a scale of days to hours, and kill fewer people.[8][11] Such warning saves people, but not immovable property.[12] This suggests that killing people does long-lasting economic harm, while destroying capital is not as harmful to GDP growth.
"Destroy any amount of physical capital, but leave behind a critical number of knowledgeable human beings whose brains still house the culture and technology of a dynamic economy, and the physical capital will tend to reemerge almost spontaneously" — George Horwich, Purdue University[9][13]
Even in disasters with few physical injuries, a large portion of the economic cost may be public health effects (approximately a tenth, in the case of the summer 2007 floods in the UK). The economic costs of disruption to children's education are significant.[14] Mental health issues may be triggered or exacerbated by the distress suffered during the disaster.[15] Health advice on minimizing psychosocial stress has been given for disasters.[16] While public health costs may contribute to economic activity and GDP growth, growth in demand for medical or educational assistance is unlikely to be seen as beneficial.
Opportunity cost of war
editOccasionally the argument has been made that war is a benefactor to society and that "war is good for the economy." A variant of this argument suggests that, while war cannot be fairly called a benefactor, it can and sometimes does confer some economic benefits.[17] However, this belief is often given as an example of the broken window fallacy. The money spent on the war effort (or peacetime defense spending), for example, is money that cannot be spent on food, clothing, health care, or other sectors of the economy. The stimulus felt in one sector of the economy comes at a direct – but hidden – cost (via foreclosed production possibilities) to other sectors.
Bastiat himself argued against the claim that hiring men to be soldiers was inherently beneficial to the economy in the second chapter of That Which is Seen, and That Which is Not Seen, "The Disbanding of Troops".
According to Hazlitt:
It is never an advantage to have one’s plants destroyed by shells or bombs unless those plants have already become valueless or acquired a negative value by depreciation and obsolescence. ... Plants and equipment cannot be replaced by an individual (or a socialist government) unless he or it has acquired or can acquire the savings, the capital accumulation, to make the replacement. But war destroys accumulated capital. ... Complications should not divert us from recognizing the basic truth that the wanton destruction of anything of real value is always a net loss, a misfortune, or a disaster, and whatever the offsetting considerations in a particular instance, can never be, on net balance, a boon or a blessing.[18]
See also
editReferences
edit- ^ a b Bastiat 1850.
- ^ Le Moniteur Industriel was a famous protectionist journal.
- ^ Fetter 1915, chapter 37: "Waste and Luxury".
- ^ Hazlitt 1946, chapter 2: "The Broken Window".
- ^ Hazlitt 1946, "Preface".
- ^ "Japan and the economics of natural disaster". The Economist. 16 March 2011.
- ^ Burn-Callander, Rebecca (28 December 2015). "UK flooding: cost of damage to top £5bn but many homes and businesses underinsured" – via www.telegraph.co.uk.
- ^ a b c d Bennett, Drake (6 July 2008). "How disasters help". The Boston Globe.
- ^ a b "Special Report: Advanced economies cope better with disasters". Reuters. 13 March 2011 – via www.reuters.com.
- ^ "The Broken Window Fallacy: Economics, Investment and Disaster Risk Reduction". ACS-AEC – www.acs-aec.org.
- ^ a b Skidmore, Mark; Toya, Hideki (October 2002). "Do natural disasters promote long-term growth?". Economic Inquiry. 40 (4): 664–687. doi:10.1093/ei/40.4.664. ISSN 1465-7295.
- ^ SciDev.Net. "Early warning of disasters: Facts and figures". SciDev.Net.
- ^ Horwich, George (April 2000). "Economic Lessons of the Kobe Earthquake". Economic Development and Cultural Change. 48 (3): 521–542. doi:10.1086/452609. JSTOR 10.1086/452609. S2CID 154588521.
- ^ "The costs of the summer 2007 floods in England". GOV.UK.
- ^ Stanke, Carla; Murray, Virginia; Amlôt, Richard; Nurse, Jo; Williams, Richard (30 May 2012). "The Effects of Flooding on Mental Health: Outcomes and Recommendations from a Review of the Literature". PLOS Currents Disasters. 4: e4f9f1fa9c3cae. doi:10.1371/4f9f1fa9c3cae (inactive 1 November 2024). ISSN 2157-3999. PMC 3461973. PMID 23066515. Retrieved 7 February 2018.
{{cite journal}}
: CS1 maint: DOI inactive as of November 2024 (link) - ^ https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/483387/Health_advice_about_mental_health_following_floods_2015.pdf[permanent dead link ] [bare URL PDF]
- ^ See for example economist Paul Krugman's article in which he refers to the Fukushima disaster in Japan: "Meltdown Macroeconomics". 15 March 2011. And another in which he refers to the 9-11 attacks: Krugman, Paul (14 September 2001). "Reckonings: After The Horror". The New York Times.
- ^ Hazlitt 1946, chapter 3: "The Blessings of Destruction".
Bibliography
edit- Bastiat, Frédéric (1850). [original French: Ce qu'on voit et ce qu'on ne voit pas]. Translated by Patrick James Stirling – via Wikisource.
- Hazlitt, Henry (1946). Economics in One Lesson. Harper & Brothers. LCCN 46005937. (PDF)
- Fetter, Frank A. (1915). Economic Principles. New York: The Century Co.
Further reading
edit- Abrams, Burton A; Parsons, George R (2009). "Is CARS a Clunker?". The Economists' Voice. 6 (8). doi:10.2202/1553-3832.1638. S2CID 153780636.
- McGee, Robert W. (2010). "Financial Bailouts and the philosophy of Frédéric Bastiat". Aestimatio (1): 88–97. SSRN 2435748.
- Stringham, Edward P.; Snow, Nicholas A. (2008). "The broken trailer fallacy: Seeing the unseen effects of government policies in post-Katrina New Orleans". International Journal of Social Economics. 35 (7): 480–89. doi:10.1108/03068290810886885. S2CID 112186379.
- Carabini, Louis (2007). "Bastiat's 'The Broken Window': A Critique" (PDF). Journal of Libertarian Studies. 21 (4): 151–55.
- Mian, Atif R.; Sufi, Amir (2010). "The Effects of Fiscal Stimulus: Evidence from the 2009 'Cash for Clunkers' Program". SSRN. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1670759. S2CID 219352572.
- Caplan, Bryan; Stringham, Edward (2005). "Mises, bastiat, public opinion, and public choice" (PDF). Review of Political Economy. 17: 79–105. doi:10.1080/0953825042000313825. S2CID 17228008.
- Stanfield, James (2010). "The Broken University: What is Seen and What is Not Seen in the Uk Higher Education Sector". Economic Affairs. 30 (3): 53–58. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0270.2010.02022.x. S2CID 153198128.
External links
edit- "Ce qu'on voit et ce qu'on ne voit pas" (original essay)
- "That Which is Seen and That Which is Not Seen" (English translation)